Volume 25, Issue 2 (Summer 2020)                   JPBUD 2020, 25(2): 3-24 | Back to browse issues page


XML Persian Abstract Print


Download citation:
BibTeX | RIS | EndNote | Medlars | ProCite | Reference Manager | RefWorks
Send citation to:

Amiri H, Samadian F. (2020). The Impact of Electoral Cycle Occurrence on Macroeconomic Environment: Case Study of Iran. JPBUD. 25(2), 3-24. doi:10.52547/jpbud.25.2.3
URL: http://jpbud.ir/article-1-1804-en.html
1- Assistant Professor Department of Economics and Islamic Banking, Faculty of Economics, University of Kharazmi, Tehran, Iran, , h.amiri@khu.ac.ir
2- M.A. in Economics, Faculty of Economics, University of Allameh Tabataba'i, Tehran, Iran.
Abstract:   (3158 Views)
The Political business cycle theory is one of the controversial topics in modern economic theory. The political business cycle, as a political factor, influences the trends of economic variables. According to economic theories, the economic policy adopted by government before election, is an expansionary one, leading to lower taxes and unemployment; it also increases consumption per capita, GDP, and the subsidies granted by the government. However, after each election, the government adopts a restrictive policy. This paper introduces the major models used to describe and analyze political and economic cycles. Moreover, Iran's political cycles and their impact on economic development are analyzed based on the BVAR model for the period 1979-2015. According to the analysis, it is concluded that the economic variables, particularly inflation and exchange rate, are under the influence of political decisions, specifically during the election period.
Full-Text [PDF 1690 kb]   (982 Downloads)    
Type of Study: Applicable | Subject: Macroeconomics
Received: Aug 08 2019 | Accepted: Sep 06 2020 | ePublished: Feb 17 2021

References
1. Alesina, A., Roubini, N., & Cohen, G. D. (1997). Political Cycles and the Macroeconomy: MIT Press. [DOI:10.7551/mitpress/5437.001.0001]
2. Beck, N. (1987). Elections and The Fed: Is There a Political Monetary Cycle? American Journal of Political Science, 31(1), 194-216. [DOI:10.2307/2111330]
3. Bohn, F. (2018). Political Cycles: Beyond Rational Expectations. PloS One, 13(10), e0203390. [DOI:10.1371/journal.pone.0203390]
4. Bonomo, M., & Terra, C. (1999). The Political Economy of Exchange Rate Policy in Brazil: An Empirical Assessment. Revista Brasileira de Economia, 53(4), 411-432. [DOI:10.1590/S0034-71401999000400001]
5. Brender, A., & Drazen, A. (2005). Political Budget Cycles in New Versus Established Democracies. Journal of Monetary Economics, 52(7), 1271-1295. [DOI:10.1016/j.jmoneco.2005.04.004]
6. Caporale, T., & Poitras, M. (2014). Voter Turnout in US Presidential Elections: Does Carville's Law Explain the Time Series? Applied Economics, 46(29), 3630-3638. [DOI:10.1080/00036846.2014.937037]
7. Cukierman, A., & Meltzer, A. H. (1986). A Theory of Ambiguity, Credibility, and Inflation under Discretion and Asymmetric Information. Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society, 54(5), 1099-1128. [DOI:10.2307/1912324]
8. De Donder, P., & Hindriks, J. (2007). Equilibrium Social Insurance with Policy-Motivated Parties. European Journal of Political Economy, 23(3), 624-640. [DOI:10.1016/j.ejpoleco.2007.02.002]
9. Doan, T., Litterman, R., & Sims, C. (1984). Forecasting and Conditional Projection Using Realistic Prior Distributions. Econometric Reviews, 3(1), 1-100. [DOI:10.1080/07474938408800053]
10. Drazen, A. (2000). The Political Business Cycle after 25 Years. NBER Macroeconomics Annual, 15(1), 75-117. [DOI:10.1086/654407]
11. Eklou, K., & Joanis, M. (2019). Do Fiscal Rules Cause Fiscal Discipline Over the Electoral Cycle? IMF Working Paper No. 19/291. [DOI:10.5089/9781513523736.001]
12. Elinder, M. (2010). Local Economies and General Elections: The Influence of Municipal and Regional Economic Conditions on Voting in Sweden 1985-2002. European Journal of Political Economy, 26(2), 279-292. [DOI:10.1016/j.ejpoleco.2010.01.003]
13. Frey, B. S., & Schneider, F. (1978). An Empirical Study of Politico-Economic Interaction in the United States. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 60(2), 174-183. [DOI:10.2307/1924970]
14. Garrett, G., & Lange, P. (1989). Government Partisanship and Economic Performance: When and How Does" Who Governs" Matter? The Journal of Politics, 51(3), 676-693. [DOI:10.2307/2131501]
15. Heckelman, J. C., & Berument, H. (1998). Political Business Cycles and Endogenous Elections. Southern Economic Journal, 64(4), 987-1000. [DOI:10.1002/j.2325-8012.1998.tb00115.x]
16. Hibbs Jr, D. A. (1977). Political Parties and Macroeconomic Policy. The American Political Science Review, 71(4), 1467-1487. [DOI:10.1017/S0003055400269712]
17. Immergut, E. M., & Jochem, S. (2006). The Political Frame for Negotiated Capitalism: Electoral Reform and the Politics of Crisis in Japan and Sweden. Governance, 19(1), 99-133. [DOI:10.1111/j.1468-0491.2006.00305.x]
18. Leigh, A., & Neill, C. (2011). Can National Infrastructure Spending Reduce Local Unemployment? Evidence from an Australian Roads Program. Economics Letters, 113(2), 150-153. [DOI:10.1016/j.econlet.2011.05.037]
19. Lindbeck, A. (1976). Stabilization Policy in Open Economies with Endogenous Politicians. The American Economic Review, 66(2), 1-19.
20. Litterman, R. B. (1986). Forecasting with Bayesian Vector Autoregressions-Five Years of Experience. Journal of Business & Economic Statistics, 4(1), 25-38. [DOI:10.1080/07350015.1986.10509491]
21. Nordhaus, W. D. (1975). The Political Business Cycle. The Review of Economic Studies, 42(2), 169-190. [DOI:10.2307/2296528]
22. Pastor, L., & Veronesi, P. (2017). Political Cycles and Stock Returns (0898-2937). NBER Working Paper Series, No, 23184 [DOI:10.3386/w23184]
23. Persons, W. M. (1926). Theories of Business Fluctuations: I. A Classification of the Theories. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 41(1), 94-128. [DOI:10.2307/1885554]
24. Persson, T., & Tabellini, G. (1992). The Politics of 1992: Fiscal Policy and European Integration. The Review of Economic Studies, 59(4), 689-701. [DOI:10.2307/2297993]
25. Potrafke, N. (2010). The Growth of Public Health Expenditures in OECD Countries: Do Government Ideology and Electoral Motives Matter? Journal of Health Economics, 29(6), 797-810. [DOI:10.1016/j.jhealeco.2010.07.008]
26. Rogoff, K. (1987). Equilibrium Political Budget Cycles (0898-2937). NBER Working Paper Series, No. 2428 [DOI:10.3386/w2428]
27. Rogoff, K., & Sibert, A. (1988). Elections and Macroeconomic Policy Cycles. The Review of Economic Studies, 55(1), 1-16. [DOI:10.2307/2297526]
28. Sibert, A. (1992). Government Finance in a Common Currency Area. Journal of International Money and Finance, 11(6), 567-578. [DOI:10.1016/0261-5606(92)90004-H]
29. Sims, C. A. (1980). Macroeconomics and Reality. Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society, 48(1), 1-48. [DOI:10.2307/1912017]
30. Sims, C. A., & Zha, T. (1998). Bayesian Methods for Dynamic Multivariate Models. International Economic Review, 39(4), 949-968. [DOI:10.2307/2527347]
31. Sims, C. A., Stock, J. H., & Watson, M. W. (1990). Inference in Linear Time Series Models with Some Unit Roots. Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society, 58(1), 113-144. [DOI:10.2307/2938337]
32. Stein, E. H., & Streb, J. M. (1998). Political Stabilization Cycles in High-Inflation Economies. Journal of Development Economics, 56(1), 159-180. [DOI:10.1016/S0304-3878(98)00057-1]

Rights and permissions
Creative Commons License This work is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License.

© 2024 CC BY-NC 4.0 | Planning and Budgeting

Designed & Developed by : Yektaweb