1. Alesina, A., Roubini, N., & Cohen, G. D. (1997). Political Cycles and the Macroeconomy: MIT Press. [
DOI:10.7551/mitpress/5437.001.0001]
2. Beck, N. (1987). Elections and The Fed: Is There a Political Monetary Cycle? American Journal of Political Science, 31(1), 194-216. [
DOI:10.2307/2111330]
3. Bohn, F. (2018). Political Cycles: Beyond Rational Expectations. PloS One, 13(10), e0203390. [
DOI:10.1371/journal.pone.0203390]
4. Bonomo, M., & Terra, C. (1999). The Political Economy of Exchange Rate Policy in Brazil: An Empirical Assessment. Revista Brasileira de Economia, 53(4), 411-432. [
DOI:10.1590/S0034-71401999000400001]
5. Brender, A., & Drazen, A. (2005). Political Budget Cycles in New Versus Established Democracies. Journal of Monetary Economics, 52(7), 1271-1295. [
DOI:10.1016/j.jmoneco.2005.04.004]
6. Caporale, T., & Poitras, M. (2014). Voter Turnout in US Presidential Elections: Does Carville's Law Explain the Time Series? Applied Economics, 46(29), 3630-3638. [
DOI:10.1080/00036846.2014.937037]
7. Cukierman, A., & Meltzer, A. H. (1986). A Theory of Ambiguity, Credibility, and Inflation under Discretion and Asymmetric Information. Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society, 54(5), 1099-1128. [
DOI:10.2307/1912324]
8. De Donder, P., & Hindriks, J. (2007). Equilibrium Social Insurance with Policy-Motivated Parties. European Journal of Political Economy, 23(3), 624-640. [
DOI:10.1016/j.ejpoleco.2007.02.002]
9. Doan, T., Litterman, R., & Sims, C. (1984). Forecasting and Conditional Projection Using Realistic Prior Distributions. Econometric Reviews, 3(1), 1-100. [
DOI:10.1080/07474938408800053]
10. Drazen, A. (2000). The Political Business Cycle after 25 Years. NBER Macroeconomics Annual, 15(1), 75-117. [
DOI:10.1086/654407]
11. Eklou, K., & Joanis, M. (2019). Do Fiscal Rules Cause Fiscal Discipline Over the Electoral Cycle? IMF Working Paper No. 19/291. [
DOI:10.5089/9781513523736.001]
12. Elinder, M. (2010). Local Economies and General Elections: The Influence of Municipal and Regional Economic Conditions on Voting in Sweden 1985-2002. European Journal of Political Economy, 26(2), 279-292. [
DOI:10.1016/j.ejpoleco.2010.01.003]
13. Frey, B. S., & Schneider, F. (1978). An Empirical Study of Politico-Economic Interaction in the United States. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 60(2), 174-183. [
DOI:10.2307/1924970]
14. Garrett, G., & Lange, P. (1989). Government Partisanship and Economic Performance: When and How Does" Who Governs" Matter? The Journal of Politics, 51(3), 676-693. [
DOI:10.2307/2131501]
15. Heckelman, J. C., & Berument, H. (1998). Political Business Cycles and Endogenous Elections. Southern Economic Journal, 64(4), 987-1000. [
DOI:10.1002/j.2325-8012.1998.tb00115.x]
16. Hibbs Jr, D. A. (1977). Political Parties and Macroeconomic Policy. The American Political Science Review, 71(4), 1467-1487. [
DOI:10.1017/S0003055400269712]
17. Immergut, E. M., & Jochem, S. (2006). The Political Frame for Negotiated Capitalism: Electoral Reform and the Politics of Crisis in Japan and Sweden. Governance, 19(1), 99-133. [
DOI:10.1111/j.1468-0491.2006.00305.x]
18. Leigh, A., & Neill, C. (2011). Can National Infrastructure Spending Reduce Local Unemployment? Evidence from an Australian Roads Program. Economics Letters, 113(2), 150-153. [
DOI:10.1016/j.econlet.2011.05.037]
19. Lindbeck, A. (1976). Stabilization Policy in Open Economies with Endogenous Politicians. The American Economic Review, 66(2), 1-19.
20. Litterman, R. B. (1986). Forecasting with Bayesian Vector Autoregressions-Five Years of Experience. Journal of Business & Economic Statistics, 4(1), 25-38. [
DOI:10.1080/07350015.1986.10509491]
21. Nordhaus, W. D. (1975). The Political Business Cycle. The Review of Economic Studies, 42(2), 169-190. [
DOI:10.2307/2296528]
22. Pastor, L., & Veronesi, P. (2017). Political Cycles and Stock Returns (0898-2937). NBER Working Paper Series, No, 23184 [
DOI:10.3386/w23184]
23. Persons, W. M. (1926). Theories of Business Fluctuations: I. A Classification of the Theories. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 41(1), 94-128. [
DOI:10.2307/1885554]
24. Persson, T., & Tabellini, G. (1992). The Politics of 1992: Fiscal Policy and European Integration. The Review of Economic Studies, 59(4), 689-701. [
DOI:10.2307/2297993]
25. Potrafke, N. (2010). The Growth of Public Health Expenditures in OECD Countries: Do Government Ideology and Electoral Motives Matter? Journal of Health Economics, 29(6), 797-810. [
DOI:10.1016/j.jhealeco.2010.07.008]
26. Rogoff, K. (1987). Equilibrium Political Budget Cycles (0898-2937). NBER Working Paper Series, No. 2428 [
DOI:10.3386/w2428]
27. Rogoff, K., & Sibert, A. (1988). Elections and Macroeconomic Policy Cycles. The Review of Economic Studies, 55(1), 1-16. [
DOI:10.2307/2297526]
28. Sibert, A. (1992). Government Finance in a Common Currency Area. Journal of International Money and Finance, 11(6), 567-578. [
DOI:10.1016/0261-5606(92)90004-H]
29. Sims, C. A. (1980). Macroeconomics and Reality. Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society, 48(1), 1-48. [
DOI:10.2307/1912017]
30. Sims, C. A., & Zha, T. (1998). Bayesian Methods for Dynamic Multivariate Models. International Economic Review, 39(4), 949-968. [
DOI:10.2307/2527347]
31. Sims, C. A., Stock, J. H., & Watson, M. W. (1990). Inference in Linear Time Series Models with Some Unit Roots. Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society, 58(1), 113-144. [
DOI:10.2307/2938337]
32. Stein, E. H., & Streb, J. M. (1998). Political Stabilization Cycles in High-Inflation Economies. Journal of Development Economics, 56(1), 159-180. [
DOI:10.1016/S0304-3878(98)00057-1]